Sunday, January 6, 2013 — Thoughts Generated by Icelandic Shnapps

The fol­low­ing is inspired by my vis­it to Ice­land, but will draw on oth­er expe­ri­ences as well. I still have a bot­tle of Ice­landic Schnapps (“with the good­ness of lichen”), which nobody else I know here in Toron­to is will­ing to drink. I will take a small nip of it every time I fin­ish a paragraph.

I vis­it­ed Ice­land because I had long been fas­ci­nat­ed by its pecu­liar his­to­ry. Its medieval sta­tus as a non-aris­to­crat­ic repub­lic, with unique elec­toral and judi­cial fea­tures, far dif­fer­ent from the urban republics of Italy, com­mends it to any his­to­ri­an of democ­ra­cy. Var­i­ous fea­tures of mod­ern Ice­land are equal­ly inter­est­ing. Con­se­quent­ly, I had been read­ing about Ice­landic his­to­ry and cul­ture for decades before I set foot in the place. One of the rea­sons I was attract­ed to study­ing the his­to­ry and soci­ety of Ice­land was its les­son that a coun­try with a pop­u­la­tion as small as 300,000, blessed with few nat­ur­al resources or strate­gic advan­tages, can pro­vide its cit­i­zens with pret­ty much any­thing they would need in the mod­ern world. While it can­not offer its cit­i­zens air­craft car­ri­ers or lin­ear accel­er­a­tors, it can eas­i­ly pro­vide most of the things that peo­ple in this cen­tu­ry con­sid­er nec­es­sary for a good life. Most of these bless­ings are patent­ly trace­able to its com­mit­ment to, and expe­ri­ence with, effec­tive demo­c­ra­t­ic insti­tu­tions. This les­son is a very impor­tant one for peo­ple in small nations, espe­cial­ly post-colo­nial ones, who yearn for both eco­nom­ic devel­op­ment and the estab­lish­ment of sol­id demo­c­ra­t­ic insti­tu­tions. Ice­land spent many cen­turies as a colony, and many cen­turies in pover­ty. It’s com­plete inde­pen­dence arrived only in the mid-twen­ti­eth cen­tu­ry. It’s achieve­ments since then have, on the whole, been very impressive. 

But not all has been a smooth ascent. In recent times, local Con­ser­v­a­tive ide­o­logues gained con­trol of the coun­try, and imple­ment­ed the crack­pot agen­da of Mil­ton Fried­man and Alan Greenspan, with­out any sig­nif­i­cant coun­ter­vail­ing forces to oppose them, to force com­pro­mis­es, or to tem­per their fanati­cism. (For­tu­nate­ly, they were not accom­pa­nied by the reli­gious, racist, and mil­i­tarist nut­bar fac­tions that par­tic­i­pate in the same move­ment in its Amer­i­can ver­sion.) The result was more or less the same as what you would expect when a coun­try is tak­en over by Marx­ists. After an ini­tial peri­od of arti­fi­cial­ly gen­er­at­ed boom-times, waste and fraud ran ram­pant. The rich, with access to an unmon­i­tored and unreg­u­lat­ed bank­ing and finan­cial sys­tem quick­ly con­coct­ed a host of scams that defraud­ed not only Ice­landers, but mil­lions of small investors in Britain, the Nether­lands, and oth­er coun­tries. The Con­ser­v­a­tive ide­ol­o­gists made a pig’s break­fast of the country’s bank­ing and finance insti­tu­tions, and pre­cip­i­tat­ed a dev­as­tat­ing finan­cial cri­sis. But once the whack-a-doo­dle Con­ser­v­a­tives were dri­ven out of office, the coun­try was able to recov­er and cor­rect itself with remark­able speed. Only four years after the cri­sis, Ice­land has among the high­est employ­ment lev­els in Europe, its finances are in tol­er­a­ble order, and it’s pop­u­la­tion has not under­gone any severe hard­ships. Seri­ous prob­lems remain, espe­cial­ly with its cur­ren­cy, which is still worth­less on the glob­al mar­ket. Some long-term prob­lems will emerge, as there are no mag­ic solu­tions to the dam­age that has been done, and the cur­rent admin­is­tra­tion is nei­ther omni­scient nor nec­es­sar­i­ly cor­rect in its poli­cies. Much of the imag­i­nary wealth that the coun­try briefly thought it had has evap­o­rat­ed, and many who lived off pix­ie dust have had to make an abrupt adjust­ment to real­i­ty. But nobody was dri­ven from their homes, as so many were in the Unit­ed States. When I arrived in the fall of 2012, I found a coun­try that was still pleas­ant and essen­tial­ly opti­mistic, though per­haps a lit­tle more cynical.

While in Ice­land, I was able to speak to an extra­or­di­nary vari­ety of peo­ple, from farm­ers and fish­er­men, to his­to­ri­ans and gov­ern­ment peo­ple. All these con­ver­sa­tions were fruit­ful. I also found that my imag­ined, dis­tance-inspired affec­tion for the place was sup­plant­ed by a real-expe­ri­ence affec­tion. The tex­ture changed, but the essence did not: I will always remain very fond of Iceland. 

But, to begin with, I’ll call up the mem­o­ry of my ear­li­est expe­ri­ence of democracy.

When I was a small child, in North­ern Ontario, there was a game played by the local chil­dren. It was a com­pli­cat­ed ver­sion of “hide-and-go-seek”. Two teams of chil­dren would form up, one of which would leave a cen­tral gath­er­ing point on a com­pli­cat­ed trail, and select a hid­ing place, leav­ing team mem­bers at strate­gic points, also hid­den. One of their num­ber would then return to the cen­tral point, meet­ing up with the oth­er team. He or she (while the game most­ly appealed to boys, girls were not exclud­ed) would then draw a map on the ground, hon­est­ly rep­re­sent­ing the hiders’ route to their points of con­ceal­ment, but omit­ting the cru­cial infor­ma­tion of com­pass direc­tion. With this par­tial infor­ma­tion, the oth­er team would set out in search, under the direc­tion of a leader. The leader of the hid­ing team would accom­pa­ny the search­ing team. He or she would shout out cod­ed words and phras­es, which had been agreed upon by his or her team mates. These would con­vey infor­ma­tion such as “the searchers are near but head­ed away from you” or “they are search­ing too far to the south of you”, etc. Some of the sig­nals were mean­ing­less, meant to mis­lead or con­fuse the searchers. The search­ing team also made use of cod­ed sig­nals to co-ordi­nate their search. One sig­nal, how­ev­er, was cru­cial, as it would trig­ger a mad scram­ble to reach the map and erase it. This was com­pli­cat­ed by the abil­i­ty of any scout to tag anoth­er, mak­ing him “freeze” on the spot, and the abil­i­ty of any oth­er scout to “unfreeze” the frozen ones. Nei­ther team knew, at first, who would become leader of the oth­er team, since each had been select­ed after they had sep­a­rat­ed. Each team made use of var­i­ous rus­es, with scouts and lead­ers act­ing in var­i­ous ways to con­fuse their oppo­site numbers.

It was an amaz­ing­ly com­plex game for small chil­dren to play. I don’t know if it is still played. Lat­er, as an adult, inves­ti­ga­tion led me to con­clude that the game was of Native Cana­di­an ori­gin. This came as no sur­prise to me, as its ele­ments are par­tic­u­lar­ly suit­ed to the Cana­di­an phys­i­cal envi­ron­ment and to its Native cul­tur­al envi­ron­ment. The hunt­ing and track­ing ele­ment, and the reliance on grasp­ing the “high view” of a land­scape are both significant.

But what is rel­e­vant here is that the game was as much a train­ing for democ­ra­cy as it was for hunt­ing and track­ing. Each stage of the game was char­ac­ter­ized by a for­mal elec­toral process. Each team leader was elect­ed by major­i­ty vote in each cycle of the game, and no leader could serve more than one con­sec­u­tive “term”. Nom­i­na­tion and vot­ing were car­ried out by spe­cif­ic pro­ce­dures which, in lat­er life, as a his­to­ri­an, I found doc­u­ment­ed among Native and Métis peo­ples in the Cana­di­an north. It was to no team’s advan­tage to keep choos­ing the same peo­ple for the same tasks — the pat­tern would soon be use­ful to the oppo­si­tion. But at the same time, a com­pe­tent or expe­ri­enced per­son was the opti­mal choice. Wild­ly com­pet­i­tive as the game was, it was also char­ac­ter­ized by a con­sis­tent demand for fair­ness and equi­ty. It is sig­nif­i­cant that nobody doubt­ed that the map drawn in the ground would be an hon­est representation. 

I grew up with this game as part of my men­tal fur­ni­ture, and it came as a sur­prise to me when I found whole pop­u­la­tions of peo­ple who had no child­hood expe­ri­ence with any kind of demo­c­ra­t­ic com­po­nent. Their child­hoods, I came to real­ize, were dom­i­nat­ed by the expe­ri­ence of tyran­ny: par­ents lay­ing down the law at home; teach­ers lay­ing down the law in school; bul­lies lay­ing down the law every­where else. It is no won­der that many peo­ple have great dif­fi­cul­ty deal­ing with the con­cept of democ­ra­cy. It is no won­der that many peo­ple today can­not imag­ine democ­ra­cy as any­thing more than some incom­pre­hen­si­ble riga­ma­role pre­ced­ing the appoint­ment of a tyrant, who will then tell them what to do.

It is this child­hood expe­ri­ence, I believe, that is the root of my life-long inter­est in the phi­los­o­phy and his­to­ry of democ­ra­cy, and which even­tu­al­ly brought me to Ice­land. It also pre­pared me for the one sig­nif­i­cant insight that has dri­ven my work since the mid 1980s: that democ­ra­cy can best be under­stood as a cul­tur­al­ly diverse phe­nom­e­non, with roots in small-scale behav­iour. It’s eti­ol­o­gy tran­scends the stan­dard con­nect-the-dots his­to­ry from Athens to mod­ern Par­lia­ments and Con­gress­es. Since that time, I’ve found sig­nif­i­cant exam­ples of demo­c­ra­t­ic prac­tices on every con­ti­nent and in almost every his­tor­i­cal peri­od. Oth­ers arrived at the same con­clu­sions inde­pen­dent­ly — pre­cise­ly what you would expect with an idea whose time has come. The work on the sub­ject that Steve Muhlberg­er and I did in the ear­ly 1990s pre­saged what is now a pow­er­ful trend among his­to­ri­ans of democ­ra­cy. This has giv­en a good deal of hope to those strug­gling against aris­to­crat­ic rule in many places on our globe. 

Much has been writ­ten about the Ice­landic Com­mon­wealth of the Mid­dle Ages. Most­ly, his­to­ri­ans have expressed their doubts that the arrange­ment which began in 930 A.D., and sur­vived until 1262 A.D. was “tru­ly” demo­c­ra­t­ic. This is, I believe, a bit of a red her­ring. When we research the his­to­ry of democ­ra­cy, we are not study­ing per­fect­ed sys­tems or utopias, we are study­ing the efforts of peo­ple to make deci­sions with­out aris­to­crat­ic rule. For more than three cen­turies, the tiny pop­u­la­tion of Ice­land man­aged its own affairs using elec­toral and rep­re­sen­ta­tive meth­ods, while the bulk of Euro­peans obeyed hered­i­tary aris­toc­ra­cies. This is not a fleet­ing instance in time. The Unit­ed States of Amer­i­ca has only exist­ed for 237 years, and Cana­da for only 146. Iceland’s medieval demo­c­ra­t­ic cul­ture even­tu­al­ly end­ed, as the inde­pen­dence of its farm­ers slow­ly erod­ed, and pow­er drift­ed into the hands of a few fam­i­lies. These fam­i­lies tore apart the Com­mon­wealth with the vio­lence of their feuds, until the Ice­landic Alþin­gi (it’s par­lia­ment) signed a Covenant (Gam­li sáttmáli) of union with the Nor­we­gian kings. Yet Ice­landic soci­ety func­tioned well enough for more than two cen­turies before this came to pass, and archae­o­log­i­cal evi­dence con­firms that this was a peri­od of rel­a­tive pros­per­i­ty for the Ice­landers. One need only com­pare George Wash­ing­ton and Thomas Jef­fer­son to George W. Bush, Jr. to see that promis­ing democ­ra­cies can be sub­ject to dra­mat­ic decay, espe­cial­ly if the cen­ter of pow­er drifts from the many to the few. Vio­la­tions of the most fun­da­men­tal prin­ci­ples of democ­ra­cy are now accept­ed by Amer­i­cans and Cana­di­ans with an emp­ty-head­ed shrug: for exam­ple, our Con­ser­v­a­tive Prime Min­is­ter in Cana­da not only vio­lat­ed the most sacred prin­ci­ple of our democ­ra­cy by arro­gant­ly refus­ing to obey Par­lia­ment, but he has cav­a­lier­ly hand­ed con­trol of our key nat­ur­al resources to the Com­mu­nist Par­ty in Bei­jing. Sim­i­lar aris­to­crat­ic abom­i­na­tions in the Unit­ed States are too numer­ous to catalog.

It was pre­cise­ly this sort of thing that I was con­tem­plat­ing dur­ing the pleas­ant after­noon I spent at Þingvel­lir, the site of the medieval Ice­landic par­lia­ment. In keep­ing with the folk­loric nature of the insti­tu­tion, this is a site in the open air, not a build­ing. The elect­ed lögsögu­maður [lawspeak­ers] and Goðorðs­menn [rep­re­sen­ta­tive chief­tains] car­ried out their delib­er­a­tions in a val­ley cre­at­ed by the sep­a­rat­ing North Amer­i­can and Eurasian tec­ton­ic plates. The ear­ly set­tlers of Ice­land were not the lot that you would expect to set­tle dis­putes peace­ful­ly, but that is exact­ly what they even­tu­al­ly did. Over the next cen­tu­ry, vio­lence steadi­ly declined in Ice­land, as pres­tige shift­ed from one’s abil­i­ty to wield an axe in bat­tle to the abil­i­ty to wield words in a law­suit. Slav­ery dis­ap­peared from Ice­land, in fact, if not strict­ly de jure. In con­tem­po­rary Eng­land, at the time of the Dooms­day Book, ten per­cent of the pop­u­la­tion remained slaves. Vio­lent ways returned at the time of the Sturlungs, in the 13th cen­tu­ry, but there were at least two cen­turies in which Ice­land was clear­ly more peace­ful than the norm in Europe. What gen­er­at­ed this strange con­fig­u­ra­tion of events? 

The cen­tral con­cept in Con­ser­vatism, and in all Aris­to­crat­ic think­ing, is that only a minor­i­ty of human beings are valu­able. The major­i­ty of peo­ple are assumed to be sec­ondary in impor­tance, designed to be used as tools or com­modi­ties by the minor­i­ty, and ulti­mate­ly dis­pos­able. This con­cept unites all Con­ser­v­a­tive think­ing in every time and place, from the con­tem­po­rary Con­ser­v­a­tive Ide­o­logues in Cana­da or the Unit­ed States, to their equiv­a­lents in the Com­mu­nist Par­ty, the estates of the hered­i­tary nobil­i­ty of Europe, the palaces of Sau­di oil sheiks, the yachts of glob­al bil­lion­aires, or the huts of auto­crat­ic trib­al chief­tains in remote jun­gles. In today’s North Korea, you have the ulti­mate man­i­fes­ta­tion of Con­ser­v­a­tive Ide­ol­o­gy. Only the rul­ing Kim fam­i­ly, and its imme­di­ate entourage, mat­ters. The remain­ing 24,554,000 human beings in North Korea exist only to serve them. Each of these mil­lions of peo­ple is ascribed a sta­tus (Song­bun) based on their hered­i­ty back­ground for three gen­er­a­tions and on the “reli­a­bil­i­ty” of their liv­ing rel­a­tives. This deter­mines every aspect of their lives, includ­ing how much food they receive. North Korea embod­ies the Con­ser­v­a­tive idea in its purest form, but every Con­ser­v­a­tive in his­to­ry has pro­mot­ed some vari­ant, dilu­tion, or approx­i­ma­tion of this “ide­al”. It is the ulti­mate tem­plate that dri­ves things as diverse-seem­ing, but inter­re­lat­ed, as the U.S. Repub­li­can Party’s hys­ter­ics over tax­ing the rich; the Chi­nese Com­mu­nist Party’s per­se­cu­tion of Tibetan cul­ture, reli­gious minori­ties, and artists; or Vladimir Putin’s skil­ful manip­u­la­tion of a cas­trat­ed Duma. When Canada’s Prime Min­is­ter, Stephen Harp­er, dis­obeyed a direct order of Par­lia­ment (and got away with it), he was pro­claim­ing the cen­tral Con­ser­v­a­tive doc­trine clear­ly: “I am the one who counts; the rest of you, all thir­ty-four and half mil­lion Cana­di­ans, do not count. You exist only to serve me, and the inter­ests of my pals and favourites, and to car­ry out my orders.” A man like Stephen Harp­er does not have the unlim­it­ed pow­er of Kim Yong-nam, but craves it, and will use every trick in his reper­toire to enhance the pow­er that he has. The tragedy in Cana­da is not so much that Harp­er grabbed the pow­er he craved, but that his polit­i­cal oppo­si­tion fold­ed their hands and let him have it. The Cana­di­an pub­lic did not under­stand the issues, and did not care, so the oppo­si­tion par­ties did not feel com­pelled to do their job. But if Cana­di­ans had been raised and edu­cat­ed in a strong­ly demo­c­ra­t­ic ethos, they would have been furi­ous, and Harper’s pow­er grab would have been stopped. Unfor­tu­nate­ly, today’s Cana­di­ans do not grow up play­ing children’s games that teach democ­ra­cy. They grow up with a thou­sand voic­es teach­ing the les­son that brute force and fraud win the day, and that arro­gant bul­lies are to be envied and honoured.

But in some times and places the pre­car­i­ous­ness of the envi­ron­ment makes peo­ple inher­ent­ly valu­able, and the prac­tice of using peo­ple like kleenex risks the lives of even the elite. It is not sur­pris­ing that some of the most egal­i­tar­i­an social arrange­ments exist in very extreme, per­ilous envi­ron­ments. Anthro­pol­o­gists have long doc­u­ment­ed the egal­i­tar­i­an ethos of the Innu­it, the Khoi-San peo­ples of the Kala­hari, and oth­er soci­eties placed in envi­ron­ments in which sur­vival depends on the co-oper­a­tion of every hand avail­able. Such soci­eties can­not afford to casu­al­ly dis­pose of any of their num­ber, and can­not even afford to alien­ate them. Pro­claim your­self innate­ly supe­ri­or, sneer at oth­ers, and try to boss them around, then see what hap­pens when you need their help fight­ing off a polar bear. The con­ven­tion­al analy­sis of such soci­eties empha­sizes their small­ness, and it is still wide­ly believed by philoso­phers of democ­ra­cy that “prim­i­tive” demo­c­ra­t­ic insti­tu­tions are a func­tion of the size of these soci­eties. There is some truth to this, but I would argue that the val­ue placed on peo­ple as peo­ple is the sig­nif­i­cant fea­ture here, and the size of the group is a col­lat­er­al, if not a sec­ondary factor. 

Iceland’s orig­i­nal set­tlers, prob­a­bly no more than a few thou­sand, spread thin­ly across a land iso­lat­ed from the rest of Europe. It was capa­ble of sup­port­ing peo­ple through a very lim­it­ed form of agri­cul­ture, but this required every iso­lat­ed farm­stead to be very labour inten­sive. While the orig­i­nal set­tlers were war­like raiders accom­pa­nied by their ret­inues, accus­tomed to both war­fare and inter­nal vio­lence, these activ­i­ties were not very prac­ti­cal in the new envi­ron­ment. Under the new cir­cum­stances, Human beings, as just human beings, acquired a val­ue that would not have been evi­dent to most Euro­peans of the time. Kin and clients attached to the house­holds tend­ed to even­tu­al­ly get farms of their own. The set­tlers brought slaves with them, but with­in a cou­ple of gen­er­a­tions there is no evi­dence of slav­ery per­sist­ing. They, too, found them­selves inex­orably pro­mot­ed. King­ship and hered­i­tary aris­toc­ra­cy, such as were con­sol­i­dat­ing pow­er in the rest of Scan­di­navia, gained no foothold. Instead, the Ice­landers devel­oped sophis­ti­cat­ed insti­tu­tions to resolve dis­putes by debate, lit­i­ga­tion and leg­is­la­tion. All these devel­op­ments are well-record­ed in a large writ­ten lit­er­a­ture, which Ice­landers pro­duced on a per-capi­ta basis far out­strip­ping that of any Euro­pean soci­ety. In most pre-indus­tri­al lit­er­a­ture, we read almost noth­ing about peas­ants, ser­vants or any­one oth­er than aris­to­crats and cler­ics. In the Ice­landic sagas, the actions and per­son­al­i­ties of even the hum­blest are described in detail. To this day, Ice­land remains a very infor­mal, rel­a­tive­ly class­less, and gen­er­al­ly egal­i­tar­i­an-indi­vid­u­al­is­tic society.

I would argue that any group of any size has the simul­ta­ne­ous poten­tial for democ­ra­cy or tyran­ny. What deter­mines the out­come is not the size of the group, but the val­ue the group places on indi­vid­ual humans, and this is in turn deter­mined by mul­ti­ple fac­tors: a her­itage of abstract ideas, envi­ron­men­tal chal­lenges, eco­nom­ic real­i­ties, legal struc­tures, and social norms. Jim Jones’ “utopi­an” com­mu­ni­ty in Guyana com­prised few­er than a thou­sand peo­ple. It dupli­cat­ed in every detail the total­i­tar­i­an insti­tu­tions of huge empires like Mao’s Peo­ples Repub­lic of Chi­na and Hitler’s Third Reich. In Jon­estown, only Jim Jones and his close hench­men mat­tered. The small­ness of the soci­ety did not gen­er­ate either social equal­i­ty or polit­i­cal democ­ra­cy. Ulti­mate­ly, Jones was able to mur­der near­ly the entire pop­u­la­tion of his lit­tle soci­ety, poi­son­ing them after train­ing them to meek­ly go to their deaths. They had long been sub­ject­ed to brain­wash­ing that had reduced them to noth­ing­ness in the glare of his self-pro­claimed majesty. 

Size is a crit­i­cal fac­tor in any democ­ra­cy, because some demo­c­ra­t­ic process­es and struc­tures have built-in scale lim­its. Direct democ­ra­cy works well up to cer­tain size, but new prob­lems arise when that size is exceed­ed. Rep­re­sen­ta­tion has eth­i­cal and pro­ce­dur­al prob­lems at any scale, but they mul­ti­ply with increas­ing pop­u­la­tion. Cre­at­ing tiers of gov­ern­ments solves some prob­lems, only to cre­ate new and dif­fer­ent ones. Con­se­quent­ly, much debate about the nature of democ­ra­cy, and its effec­tive­ness, turns on assump­tions about what con­sti­tutes “local” and “small scale” on the one hand, and “large scale” on the oth­er. Last year, a book was pub­lished called The Secret His­to­ry of Democ­ra­cy, which con­tained chap­ters by myself and my col­league and col­lab­o­ra­tor Steven Muhlberg­er, among oth­ers. Most reviews were pos­i­tive, but a few were neg­a­tive. The neg­a­tive reviews focused on the size of the com­mu­ni­ties from which exam­ples of demo­c­ra­t­ic prac­tice were drawn. Because many of the cross-cul­tur­al exam­ples involved small com­mu­ni­ties, such as the Cana­di­an Métis in my con­tri­bu­tion, these review­ers dis­missed them as irrel­e­vant to the devel­op­ment of large-scale democ­ra­cy. The large-scale poli­ties they con­sid­er sig­nif­i­cant have long been acknowl­edged to have evolved their insti­tu­tions from sim­i­lar­ly small-scale prac­tices, but this has escaped their atten­tion. The exam­ples were “mere­ly” local democ­ra­cy, and any shmoe can do local democ­ra­cy, we are told. Only the big stuff counts. 

I don’t share this view. Rather, I believe that local democ­ra­cy is more than the prim­i­tive ances­tor of mod­ern nation­al democ­ra­cy. It should be right­ly per­ceived as the pri­ma­ry and essen­tial man­i­fes­ta­tion of democ­ra­cy, with larg­er-scale lev­els of activ­i­ty prop­er­ly under­stood as deriv­a­tive, rather than “high­er” levels.

Notions of what con­sti­tutes a “local” scale obvi­ous­ly depend on the expe­ri­ence of the per­son doing the analy­sis. To an Amer­i­can, the admin­is­tra­tive con­cerns of the 2.7 mil­lion peo­ple in Chica­go con­sti­tute “local gov­ern­ment,” and that is the sort of thing Amer­i­can the­o­rists think of as a mere ter­tiary stage in rep­re­sen­ta­tive gov­ern­ment, over­ruled by two larg­er lev­els. But the world con­tains many coun­tries that are small­er than Chica­go. Since much the­o­ret­i­cal dis­cus­sion of the nature of local gov­ern­ment emanates from the uni­ver­si­ties of large coun­tries (often with a glob­al scale impe­r­i­al past), there is a poten­tial for a dis­tort­ed inter­pre­ta­tion of norms.

Coun­tries that com­bine the high­est lev­els of democ­ra­cy with high stan­dards of liv­ing and low lev­els of cor­rup­tion tend to be in the less than 10 mil­lion pop­u­la­tion range. Den­mark (pop. less than 4.5 mil­lion) has one of the world’s high­est per capi­ta incomes as well as the world’s high­est lev­el of income equal­i­ty. It also pro­vides high qual­i­ty pub­lic ser­vices, and a com­pre­hen­sive social safe­ty and wel­fare net. It’s pri­vate busi­ness­es are known for their high degree of com­pet­i­tive­ness and tech­ni­cal inno­va­tion. It has fre­quent­ly ranked as the hap­pi­est and least cor­rupt coun­try in the world [these facts are all doc­u­ment­ed in Forbes 14 July 2010]. Trans­paren­cy Inter­na­tion­al [Transparency.org. 15 Decem­ber 2010] cites Den­mark as hav­ing the great­est lev­el of pub­lic sat­is­fac­tion in the per­for­mance of its polit­i­cal insti­tu­tions of any nation on earth. Denmark’s democ­ra­cy con­sists of a mul­ti-par­ty par­lia­men­tary sys­tem with exten­sive devo­lu­tion of pow­ers to the local lev­el. Like the Unit­ed States or Cana­da, it pos­sess­es three basic lev­els of admin­is­tra­tion (fed­er­al, region­al, and local), but the “local” lev­el encom­pass­es 98 munic­i­pal­i­ties with an aver­age of 25,000 peo­ple. Denmark’s nation­al pol­i­tics would be con­sid­ered “local” in the Unit­ed States, the Unit­ed King­dom, or France, while its local pol­i­tics would be on too micro­scop­ic a scale for any Amer­i­can or French intel­lec­tu­al to even contemplate. 

Switzer­land (pop. 8 mil­lion), anoth­er coun­try with a long and remark­able demo­c­ra­t­ic his­to­ry, also employs a three-lev­el struc­ture of com­mune, can­ton and fed­er­al lev­els. Switzerland’s fed­er­al sys­tem, estab­lished in 1848, was inspired by the Amer­i­can con­sti­tu­tion, but Switzer­land went on to devel­op com­plex insti­tu­tions of direct and semi-direct democ­ra­cy, includ­ing a pletho­ra of ref­er­en­da. The ful­crum of pow­er rests on the can­ton lev­el. The can­tons retain all pow­ers and com­pe­ten­cies not del­e­gat­ed to the Con­fed­er­a­tion by the Con­sti­tu­tion, and are respon­si­ble for health­care, wel­fare, law enforce­ment and pub­lic edu­ca­tion. Most sig­nif­i­cant­ly, they also wield the pow­er of tax­a­tion. The com­munes (= munic­i­pal­i­ties) vary great­ly in size, between 15,000 and 1,390,000. Switzer­land is an extreme­ly wealthy coun­try. Its GDP per capi­ta is near­ly dou­ble that of the Unit­ed States, and it has the high­est lev­el of wealth per adult (finan­cial and non-finan­cial assets) of any coun­try in the world. While Amer­i­can and Cana­di­an polit­i­cal the­o­rists are quick to assume that the suc­cess of the Scan­di­na­vian coun­tries is only pos­si­ble because of their “homo­gene­ity”, this claim can hard­ly be made for Switzer­land, which has four nation­al lan­guages and three major eth­nic groups that do not actu­al­ly like each oth­er very much. Far more sig­nif­i­cant is its com­mit­ment to a vig­or­ous, local­ly focused demo­c­ra­t­ic sys­tem. The 1999 con­sti­tu­tion has strength­ened the pow­ers of the fed­er­al lev­el, but it remains to be seen if this is advan­ta­geous in any way. 

The aver­age pop­u­la­tion of coun­tries in the world is 34,000,000. This aver­age fig­ure is, of course, large­ly deter­mined by the pres­ence of a hand­ful of hyper­tro­phied giants (such as Chi­na and India). It should be not­ed that one of these has made a cred­itable, though some­times rocky attempt at func­tion­ing demo­c­ra­t­i­cal­ly, while the oth­er remains a crude Con­ser­v­a­tive-Com­mu­nist dic­ta­tor­ship. While Cana­di­ans, because they sit next to the mas­sive­ly pop­u­lat­ed Unit­ed States, are accus­tomed to think of them­selves as a “small” coun­try, they are in fact, almost exact­ly the aver­age in pop­u­la­tion. Ice­land, how­ev­er, is small by anybody’s stan­dards. It’s total pop­u­la­tion is less than one of Toronto’s sub­urbs. This bears direct­ly on both some of its suc­cess­es and some of its fail­ures. Because Ice­land is so small, its “elite” is very small indeed. In fact, almost every­one with a sig­nif­i­cant influ­ence on Ice­landic soci­ety went to the same uni­ver­si­ty and even to the same high school. The wave of Con­ser­v­a­tive Ide­ol­o­gy that arrived in Ice­land was gen­er­at­ed by a small group of peo­ple, all of whom knew each oth­er inti­mate­ly. They took up roles of lead­er­ship in gov­ern­ment and busi­ness with­out any sig­nif­i­cant imped­i­ments from the old­er elite. They were pro­found­ly influ­enced by a vis­it to Ice­land made by Mil­ton Fried­man in 1984. Fried­man was invit­ed to debate some young Ice­landic econ­o­mists on nation­al tele­vi­sion. I have, by good luck, come across a tape of this debate, and I could see how such a small thing could have a pro­found impact on a small soci­ety about to change its gen­er­a­tion of lead­er­ship. Fried­man could eas­i­ly antic­i­pate the posi­tions of his debat­ing oppo­nents, and had no dif­fi­cul­ty out­ma­neu­ver­ing them. This was a small pond, and the Ice­landers were min­nows encoun­ter­ing a shark. Friedman’s ver­sion of “free­dom” had much in it to appeal to a gen­er­a­tion who had lived in Iceland’s com­fort­able, but stuffy and need­less­ly puri­tan­i­cal soci­ety. There was lit­tle rea­son for most Ice­landers to grasp that the improved night life, greater fun and appar­ent pros­per­i­ty came with bank fraud and finan­cial ruin embed­ded in its DNA. Because Ice­land was a small, rather naïve soci­ety, it was eas­i­ly vic­tim­ized by a ruth­less ide­ol­o­gy. There were no coun­ter­vail­ing forces. Once in pow­er, it had free reign. Because Ice­landers had a soci­ety in which hon­esty was the norm, they were ill-equipped to deal with pro­fes­sion­al con-men and expe­ri­enced liars. 

But, once the dam­age was done, Iceland’s small size became an advan­tage again. Sen­si­ble pal­lia­tive and cor­rec­tive mea­sures could be applied, because the soci­ety was accus­tomed to think­ing of itself as a fam­i­ly. The fraud-enriched bil­lion­aires, of course, ran off to their Man­hat­tan pent­hous­es and Riv­iera digs, leav­ing the Ice­landers alone to patch things up. The results, as I stat­ed ear­li­er, do not seem to have been bad.

It is evi­dent that giv­en the cur­rent state of devel­op­ment in demo­c­ra­t­ic prac­tice, even with the best inten­tions, and a mirac­u­lous nation­al con­sen­sus on reform, a coun­try as large as the Unit­ed States can­not achieve the lev­els of social equal­i­ty, pros­per­i­ty, admin­is­tra­tive trans­paren­cy, and gen­er­al effi­cien­cy that Danes or Nor­we­gians take for grant­ed, nor can it solve any of its major social and fis­cal prob­lems. It is not mere­ly a mat­ter of vot­ing in some bet­ter peo­ple, as it is in Iceland.

The trick in the suc­cess­ful func­tion­ing of any com­plex orga­ni­za­tion is to find the appro­pri­ate lev­el on which any giv­en action should be tak­en, and on which any deci­sion should be made. The Con­ser­v­a­tive-Author­i­tar­i­an-Sta­tist men­tal­i­ty assumes that the “default” posi­tion should be as high up the orga­ni­za­tion­al tree as pos­si­ble, while the Free­dom-Indi­vid­u­al­ist-Demo­c­ra­t­ic men­tal­i­ty assumes that it should rest as low as pos­si­ble on the tree. I do not take seri­ous­ly any claims made by Con­ser­v­a­tives to be advo­cates of “small gov­ern­ment”, of being moti­vat­ed by a desire for “free­dom” or to be “anti-sta­tist”. Con­ser­vatism is an Ide­ol­o­gy as devot­ed to sys­tem­at­ic lying as Marx­ism, and such claims are as absurd and men­da­cious as Marx­ist claims to be cham­pi­ons of the com­mon peo­ple or to pro­mote “equal­i­ty”. But the wor­ship of the large scale, and large-scale pow­er is not con­fined to such ide­o­log­i­cal zealots. While occa­sion­al lip-ser­vice is payed to “decen­tral­iza­tion,” “devo­lu­tion,” and oth­er vague notions of demo­c­ra­t­ic reform, the mind-set of most intel­lec­tu­als and pub­lic offi­cials in Cana­da and the Unit­ed States, what­ev­er their par­ty label, is still firm­ly in the Con­ser­v­a­tive-Author­i­tar­i­an-Sta­tist men­tal uni­verse. Imag­i­nary “economies of scale” and the lust to wield large units of pow­er still moti­vate most polit­i­cal ideas and decision-making.

Yet, you might notice that my eval­u­a­tion of the Unit­ed States began with “giv­en the cur­rent state of devel­op­ment in demo­c­ra­t­ic prac­tice.” That state is not fixed. Demo­c­ra­t­ic insti­tu­tions have been less suc­cess­ful in deal­ing with large num­bers of human beings because there has been lit­tle effort to mod­i­fy or improve them. For the most part, they have sim­ply been inflat­ed, with­out sig­nif­i­cant inno­va­tion. It’s as if we gave up on the idea of com­merce because you can’t man­age a mul­ti-nation­al chain with the same tech­niques as a cor­ner store. The unspo­ken assump­tion among politi­cians is that we keep our inher­it­ed demo­c­ra­t­ic prac­tices only to main­tain con­ti­nu­ity with the past, for the same rea­son the Catholic Church pub­lish­es encycli­cals in Latin. It is only recent­ly, after mil­lions of ordi­nary peo­ple in oppres­sive coun­tries have risked their lives to obtain it, that any notice­able num­ber of intel­lec­tu­als have tak­en democ­ra­cy seri­ous­ly as an idea. When Steve Muhlberg­er and I began our work, the word “democ­ra­cy” evoked noth­ing but sneers and snig­gers from the over­whelm­ing major­i­ty of intel­lec­tu­als (as it has through­out much of his­to­ry). Now, many have jumped on the band wag­on, some sin­cere­ly, though prob­a­bly just as many as a duplic­i­tous strat­e­gy. The demo­c­ra­t­ic move­ment of today, how­ev­er, is more than an intel­lec­tu­al fad. It is a gen­uine move­ment of the peo­ple, and in such a move­ment, real inno­va­tions might ges­tate and find enough sup­port to be imple­ment­ed. The prob­lem of cre­at­ing fair and egal­i­tar­i­an gov­er­nance for large groups of peo­ple may find solu­tions — per­haps a great vari­ety and choice of solu­tions — if seri­ous effort is made to find them.

Leave a Comment